Introduction.
Spending commitments.
Addressing climate change. Broadband as modern infrastructure investment. Education for life. Regressive policies. Where is the welfare system?
Addressing climate change. Broadband as modern infrastructure investment. Education for life. Regressive policies. Where is the welfare system?
Raising revenue.
95% is a good and
untruthful line. Corporate tax. Worker’s shares policy is a second corporate
tax. The average citizen and tax.
Issues of personal
interest.
Brexit policy.
Council tax. Trust on foreign policy. Paternity leave.
Conclusion.
Introduction.
The 2019
Labour manifesto has been met with the support of 160 economists and the adoration of
the party rank and file. It is a bold document designed to attack - and attack
hard - in order to make up the current gap in the polls between Labour and the
Conservatives. Contrast this with the Conservatives, who have chosen to put out
a manifesto sparse on content and detail, presumably hoping to ride their
current lead through to December 12th.
While the manifesto
is clearly radical in the rate of spending increases it proposes, and the
pledges on infrastructure investment and the climate are extremely positive,
praise for it must be qualified. Some have expressed concerns that the speed at
which the party wants to increase investment is simply not possible, since
there just aren’t the numbers of unemployed workers with the necessary skills
available. More damningly, there is woefully little on in-work benefits,
despite the party’s repeated focus on in-work poverty; there is little to make
local councils cheer; and its claims regarding revenue raising seem
questionable and in parts disingenuous. It includes policies that sound great
from a podium, but are actually regressive and represent a blatant appeal to
particular groups without much concern about the distributional consequences.
What should be singled out for nearly unqualified praise, however, is the
party’s Brexit policy, which is the position on offer that is most likely to
begin the process of healing in our country.
This post is lengthy,
as one would expect given the subject. It is of course by no means
comprehensive - it is not possible to have well-thought out positions on every
topic in British politics, let alone be able to put those thoughts in one
reasonably sized document. I’m neither a pundit nor a politician, but an
ordinary voter, so I’ve perhaps asked for far more of the reader’s time than is
reasonable, but nevertheless an account of an ordinary voter’s thoughts on a
manifesto seem important enough to be written down somewhere. I have aimed to
comment only on what is in the Labour manifesto, and not on comments that
politicians have made outside of it, with two exceptions: Corbyn’s statement
that he would remain neutral in a second referendum, and in a discussion of the
extent to which the manifesto pledges on defense policy are pledges which
voters can rely on.
Spending commitments.
Addressing climate
change.
We have recently
heard from climate experts that there’s a significant chance that the Earth has
already
passed tipping points for
the global climate. Researchers suggest that much of Teesside - the area I call
home - will be underwater in a little over thirty years. We
should be angry, we should be afraid, and we should be acting.
The Labour manifesto
opens with a full section dedicated to the environment and Labour’s take on a
‘green new deal,’ which is a very promising development and implies that
tackling climate change is a number one priority. There is little said about
adaptation beyond improving flood protection, which is unfortunate; we must
admit that we have failed to prevent at least some amount of climate emergency.
Furthermore, there is a limit to what a single country can do to prevent
serious climate change. The UK has consistently seen its emissions (even when
including carbon leakage) go down - yet world emissions have gone up.
Given this, and the warning from climate scientists on Wednesday, it is time
for parties to seriously consider what changes in infrastructure and
organisation are needed to prepare the UK for a world with some exposure to a
climate crisis. However,the absence of such a discussion is unsurprising - all
parties are unwilling to discuss this area in what may be seen in a fatalistic
way, which is most likely electorally smart. Given the extensive plans for
mitigation that the party has presented, it would be unfair to use this as a
litmus test for the sincerity of the party’s commitment to tackle and handle climate
change.
The mitigation
strategies included are comprehensive, with welcome policies on food production
and land use, transport, tree planting and nature restoration, and investment
priorities. Particularly welcome are the policies to restart state funding of
tidal wave energy production in Wales, and McDonnell’s plan to delist companies
that are failing to tackle climate change from the London Stock Exchange
(LSE).
The former policy
addresses projects for which the Conservative government has withdrawn funding,
citing problems with the return on the investment. This objection misses the
point. The cost of inaction is incalculable; the need to switch power
generation to sustainable models is urgent. The Swansea Bay tidal lagoon
project is a pioneering technology, which goes some way to explaining the high
cost, and we should bear in mind that the completion of this project will
reduce the cost of similar future projects. More than this, it is a transition
we can’t choose to not make. The threat is existential, and if the upfront
costs of challenging it are high, then we need to figure out how to pay for
them.
Similarly, the threat
to delist companies that do not do their part to address climate change is
radical but sensible. There is only so much a government is able to do through
its own action, and most economic activity is private. It is therefore
incumbent on companies to take action in the fight against climate change, and
it is reasonable to say that a requirement to be listed in the UK should be to
take responsibility for this existential threat. One may have concerns
regarding the effect on UK growth as high productivity companies retreat from
the LSE, but we can no longer sacrifice the climate for growth. Examples such
as Sweden have shown that the economy can be decoupled from greenhouse gas emissions, and
hence that growth can be achieved sustainably. Continued growth in living standards
can only be achieved sustainably, for any other method of growth will have
unacceptable consequences that will be felt by everyone in a not-too-distant
future. Even ignoring this, a fear of such flight from the LSE is easily
overstated. London will continue to be a strong attractor for publicly traded
companies. The UK’s long run economy is strong, and London’s banking hub is
massive. One can only hope that other countries would take the example given by
the UK and implement similar policies, further reducing the potential for lost
growth, as companies lose the option to pursue unsustainable methods of
production in more and more countries.
The manifesto
proposes a great number of domestic efforts the country can make to play our
role in climate change mitigation, but we must also think wider. The manifesto
comes tantalisingly close to pledging to introduce carbon border adjustments.
The intention of this is to prevent carbon leakage - the phenomenon whereby
countries that impose high carbon prices simply import carbon intensive
products from countries with low carbon prices. Carbon adjustments would
address this by imposing a tariff such that the importer pays the same carbon
price as if the product had been produced in the UK. The manifesto acknowledges
the problem of carbon leakage, and while it does not advocate carbon border
adjustments, it pledges a review into measures to address carbon leakage - an
area that has, until now, been ignored in UK political discourse. By and large,
the Labour manifesto is extremely positive on the issue of climate change.
Broadband as modern
infrastructure investment.
At first glance, the
policy to provide free broadband to all seems to be an offer of bread and
circuses, and indeed some
focus groups suggest that this is exactly how some voters perceive it. This plays
into a justified concern of Labour’s priorities that first arose during the
2017 election, when the party committed to ending tuition fees but maintaining
the benefits freeze.
The objection to the
broadband policy is not unreasonable and was perhaps exacerbated by the party’s
presentation of the policy, but ultimately the pledge represents a very reasonable,
modern infrastructure investment that has a very good analogy with road
building, and in particular with HS2.
Much like road
building, this spending would entail a high upfront cost followed by relatively
small marginal costs, and so, like road use, we would not expect a direct
charge for usage by an individual or business. The upfront cost of each
investment is justified morally by the expectation that the public is able to
easily move around the country, and economically by the growth in productivity
that greater connectivity provides. In the case of full coverage of
fibre-to-premises broadband, Open Reach estimates a £59 billion boost to UK productivity, and a £740
million boost to online sales.
The party’s intention
is to begin rollout in rural areas, then towns, and finally urban centers. This
is a sensible way to proceed. It is vital that the government addresses rural
areas which have been left behind in this area (as in so many others), and
denied the opportunities to increase living standards and to boost their
economies. While it is possibly the case that the cost-benefit analysis would not
support extension into urban centers, this is of no grave consequence to the
policy, as the government would simply be able to change course while still
having improved broadband coverage in areas that need it most.
However, the policy
is not entirely positive. As the Future
Telecoms Infrastructure Review suggests, we should be concerned that a monopoly on broadband could
eliminate the competition that is so vital in driving innovation. Far
better would be the use of public competitive enterprise - establishing a
state-owned entity to compete with private companies on broadband provision. By
providing quality free broadband, private companies would by necessity have to
improve their service to compete or fade out of the market. In turn, the
existence of these private companies should provide an upward pressure on the
quality of the state-owned enterprise. In either situation, the consumer
benefits. In the current policy - that of part nationalising BT - this upward
pressure does not exist, and we risk the standards of broadband services
declining across the UK.
Further, it does seem
somewhat strange to offer a free broadband services to households that are not
at all struggling with broadband fees. A means-tested fee seems like a
reasonable remedy to this, but may be costly and cumbersome to implement. An
alternative could be a slight increase in income tax rates to pay for this
policy, as this is already a progressive tax (in the sense that higher earners
contribute a higher proportion of their income). Of course, this would
contradict Labour’s somewhat dubious claim that only the 5% of highest earners
will see tax increases - but this is a line that Labour should quickly abandon,
as we shall discuss later.
Education for life.
Provided the funding
exists, Labour’s policy regarding education for life is the ideal retraining
policy. If we are to reap the benefits of a more globalised economy, we must
acknowledge that this is due to ‘creative destruction,’ whereby less
competitive firms are forced to close due to competition from more competitive
firms. This means not only job losses, but the loss of industries in which
former workers are likely to have specialised their labour. Retraining, at any
point in one’s life, is essential for all to share in prosperity. More than
this, to provide everyone with the best opportunity of living their most
fulfilling life, we need to allow people to change course and learn new skills,
and re-enter education when their current occupation is no longer satisfying.
There is both a moral and a distributional case for this policy, in addition to
its aggregate effects on the UK economy. Such a policy would create a much more
well-trained labour force and would massively reduce labour frictions, thereby
increasing productivity - particularly productivity in high-skilled industries
- allowing real wages to rise, and reducing unemployment. Everyone in the UK
would benefit from this scheme, be it directly or indirectly, and even if it is
not fully implementable within the next Parliament, it should remain a goal for
successive governments.
Regressive policies.
The term “student
loan” invites thoughts of a repayment scheme that is unconnected to income and
imposes an unwelcome burden to the payee. As it is, the payment of student
loans is effectively a 9% tax on annual income above £25,000 that is capped
both by the value of the student loan, and by time, with the ‘debt’ being
written off after thirty years. It is not a debt analogous to conventional
debt, and to conceive of it as such is unhelpful. Because of this structure,
abolishing tuition fees is essentially a tax break for high earning graduates.
The motivating
principle of the current structure is that those who have financially benefited
from higher education contribute to paying the cost of this investment, whereas
those who have not - either because their degree did not lead to a high
paying job or because they did not attend a higher education institution - do
not. Figures regarding low rates of repayment are often cited as evidence that
the system is failing; rather, it is evidence that the system is working as
intended. Not everyone is expected to pay this debt, only those who have
benefitted from their ‘loan’ enough to be able to pay. The state contributes to
the investment in our education and pays for it by effectively taxing those who
personally benefit - a model of taxation we should surely support. The
alternative is having the cost fall on lower earners by distributing the whole
cost evenly across taxpayers through normal taxation. As well as the
ideological case against free tuition, there is also evidence that the introduction
of tuition fees has increased working class participation in higher
education. It is also possible that to keep the costs of higher education
manageable, placements in universities would have to be capped, resulting in
lower access for poorer families.
A similar problem of
regressive effects plagues the pledges to abolish prescription fees and the
return of license fees for over-75s. As the Institute
of Fiscal Studies notes, last year, only 11% of prescriptions were subject to the £8.50
cost, with 89% of prescriptions being completely free. This is due to the
progressive system currently in place, which grants exemptions based on age,
disability, chronic illness, and employment status. By and large, those unable
to pay without such payment being a burden are able to access prescription
drugs for free, as they of course should. The abolishment of these fees
addresses a problem that doesn’t exist, and simply creates a higher,
unnecessary burden on the taxpayer.
The situation
regarding TV license payments requires more attention, but for the same reasons
as above, the restoration of free TV licenses for over 75s is not a progressive
move. As noted by the Resolution
Foundation, there is little justification for paying for the TV licenses for
better-off over 75s. It is perhaps time that Labour considers a truly
progressive change in the funding of the BBC, which would link payment of a TV
license directly to income, rather than to age. The justification for the free
licenses for over 75s presumably rests on the principle that we should protect
access to services for vulnerable people, but the relevant vulnerability here
is the ability to pay. It does not seem to make much sense that a wealthy 76
year old is provided a free TV license but a low income family is not.
These policies of
course sound good to very many. On the face of it, it does seem unfair that one
has to pay to specialise what they can contribute to society, it does seem
unfair that one has to pay for medicines, it does seem unfair that the elderly
are now expected to pay for their TV licenses. But every time the party
suggests scrapping tuition fees, there’s a lower income voter who asks why
there’s money to do that, but not to provide greater support through our
welfare system. Every time the party suggests scrapping prescription charges,
there’s a parent thinking that they already get their children’s prescriptions
for free, and if there’s money for this policy, why isn’t their money to
provide greater support through higher child benefits. And every time they
think this, they’re right, and Labour should start moving away from these
pledges.
Where is the welfare
system?
The upshot of this is
that the Labour party has failed to prioritise appropriately. The manifesto is
shockingly light on changes to benefits beyond (rightly) pledging to abandon
universal credit with the IFS estimating that the changes they have pledged amount to reversing just one quarter of the cuts implemented since 2010. There is no mention of in-work benefits or
working tax credits, despite the rhetoric the party employs around in-work
poverty. Why are these concerns behind reducing payments for high earning
graduates, or the 11% who will save £8.50 on their prescriptions? Tangentially, why is there no pledge or even comment regarding those struggling under HMRC's loan charge? The spending
on infrastructure and the green revolution is welcome and necessary, but the
lack of attention paid to the most vulnerable in our society in any materially
significant way is not. Perhaps the calculation was made that voters would
respond positively to infrastructure investment, since such spending has
tangible and highly visible results, as opposed to changes to the welfare
system which many people do not interact with in a significant way. If that’s
the case, as it seems it may well be, the branding of this manifesto as the
‘manifesto of hope’ is profoundly inaccurate.
Raising revenue.
95% is a good and
untruthful line.
The line that the
party has been pushing throughout this campaign is that 95% of people will not
pay more in taxes. This may or may not be a good line. It seems to resonate
with activists but can only be motivated by the belief that the average earner
is unwilling to contribute more for a better society, which is bleak, and is
arguably wrong. Both the Institute for Fiscal Studies and the Resolution
Foundation dispute the claim that the spending that is suggested can be funded
in this way; apparently recognised by Labour, as the manifesto contains tax
increases for those below the 95th percentile of income.
Corporate tax.
The Labour party
claims that much of the revenue will be generated through raises to corporate
tax. The belief that this doesn’t affect natural persons seems to rest on the
leadership’s assumption that natural persons don’t interact with large
corporations, seemingly imagined as entities that float above society,
inflicting only harm and damage. Of course, this is not the case. Corporations
employ people, and sell goods and services to people. Corporations also respond
to changes in taxes, and do not simply absorb them without consequence, with
their four main options being to raise prices to incorporate the tax; to reduce
wages (or at least slow down increases) to absorb the cost increase; to reduce
capital investment to absorb the cost increase; or to reduce profit.
Each of these
responses is harmful to citizens in some manner. The result of higher prices or
lower wages is obvious - reducing the spending power of consumers or reducing
the income of workers, leading to lower quality of living. It is odd that this
concern is not mitigated or acknowledged within the manifesto, given that it
rightly describes VAT as a regressive tax and pledges not to increase it over
the course of their parliament. Reductions in capital investment would not
initially harm the consumer, but eventually lead to lower productivity growth,
and hence reduce the capacity for wage increases further down the line, reducing
improvements to standards of living over time, with all the consequences that
lower growth rates entail.
One would presume
that the Labour party hopes for the latter outcome - that profits are simply
reduced. This course is perhaps the one with the least direct damage to
consumers, but has unfortunate consequences for pension schemes and those who
rely on them. Pension pots are driven up only by the performance of their
investment portfolios. A reduction in profits leads to a reduction in dividends,
which leads to weaker stock performance, which leads to weaker pension growth.
This is dangerous for those on defined contribution pensions, but particularly
dangerous for those who will rely on defined benefit schemes, which made
commitments based on an expectation of roughly similar growth as today, and may
be unable to operate when people expect to rely on them.
None of this is to
say that corporate tax shouldn’t be increased. It is only to argue that
corporate taxation doesn’t exist in a bubble, and changes to corporate tax
effect everybody, and we should be honest about this when we discuss changes.
We should be honest that to do some good, most of the time there will be an
associated bad, and we should transparently provide the information the electorate
needs to weigh up costs and benefits. Corporate tax in the UK is
extraordinarily low, and much lower than most comparable countries. The fear
that corporations would flee from the UK if we raise corporate tax to a still
comparably low rate is nonsensical. Perhaps there is a moral case for raising
corporate tax even including these consequences, or a practical case given how
changes interact with other planned changes. Perhaps they indicate that we need
to radically rethink how we tax those who benefit from company profits more
directly. But in any case, it is wrong to act as though higher corporate tax is
a free source of revenue decoupled from the rest of society.
Worker’s shares
policy is a second corporate tax.
John McDonnell’s
plans for publicly traded companies to become 10% owned by their employees
within 10 years were widely discussed on announcement long before the launch of
the manifesto, but are still useful to consider here. The outline of the plan
is that 10% of every publicly traded company with over 250 employees would be
owned by an employee ran body called an Inclusive Ownership Fund (IOF). The IOF
would receive and distribute dividends on its shares to the employees, but with
these dividend payments capped at £500 per employee per year, and the remainder
of any corresponding dividend going to the Treasury.
There are many
benefits to genuine employee ownership, such as higher productivity - likely
due to greater morale and a feeling of investment in the project - and a
greater intimacy with the business’ operations, creating better intra-company
relations. Policies to encourage genuine employee ownership and improve the
success of the cooperative movement should be welcomed with enthusiasm.
However it is hard to
describe this policy as one of genuine employee ownership. IOFs will not be
able to sell, buy, or otherwise manage their shares, and employees will not be
able to sell or manage their stake in the IOF. There are very few instances in
which you are compelled to possess a thing over which you have no control or
rights to sell which we would consider ownership. Further, due to the £500 cap,
in a majority of cases the policy will not constitute a profit-sharing
exercise, as the upper limit means that in many cases that this ‘dividend’ will
not be reflective of the company’s performance, and nor will it be an incentive
for higher productivity.
As noted by Clifford
Chance (an international law firm), the policy is best thought of as another corporate
tax. They estimate that
of the £10 billion that companies would be required to pay under this policy,
only £1 billion of this would go to workers, with the other £9 billion accruing
to the Treasury. According to their calculations, this effectively equates to a
5% tax, which, given other commitments to raising corporate tax to 26%, results
in effectively a tax of 31%, notably higher than most of our peers. Whether or
not this is a problem is for an individual voter to assess, although in this
case, fears of companies moving out of the UK and hence reducing UK
productivity growth, employment, and thereby reducing the UK tax base are a lot
more well founded, particularly given the rapid shift from relatively low
corporate tax to relatively high corporate tax. Whether or not the latter state
is better, such rapid changes rarely lack consequences.
A further unintended
consequence of this policy is that any tax structured with a discontinuity has
the effect of incentivising against growth beyond the discontinuity - in this
case 250 employees. We should be wary of any policy that reduces productivity
growth in such a way, and if Labour is intent on this scheme (rather than one
that incentivises genuine employee ownership) it should seriously consider a
scheme whereby the amount of shares held by the IOF is phased in from 0% to 10%
as a function of the number of employees. This would prevent the situation in
which a company chooses not to grow, since any growth of less than 10% would
represent an unprofitable change.
The average citizen
and tax.
This stealth tax and
the explicit raise in corporate tax, as well as the intended rise on income tax
for those earning over £80,000, are all necessary to put up the facade that 95%
of people won’t be paying more. This is a lie in any instance, due to other
planned tax changes such as scrapping a benefit for married couples and changes
to dividend tax. I firmly believe that these latter tax changes are of great
importance in addressing the fairness with which we treat couples, and to
address the unfairness of the preferential treatment currently afforded to
unearned income, but regardless of whether or not these are positive
developments, parties should be honest about how they intend to raise funds and
who the ultimate payer of these taxes are.
But the problem is
deeper than that. The motivation for such a line is the belief that people
don’t want to pay tax. A left wing party should be making the case that it is
patriotic to build a better society together; it is incumbent upon us to
convince people that the contribution to this project and to each other is a
patriotic duty, and the enjoyment of the society we can create is our right.
And there is evidence to suggest that this is a view that is shared by a
majority of UK citizens. A Fabian
Society report suggests that people link their tax payments to their citizenship, and
that they are proud to contribute to good public services. The perception of
tax as a thing that the electorate objects to is largely a result of
implementation of individual taxes. One place we see evidence of this is the
largely positive response to Gordon Brown’s 1p increase on National Insurance
in 2002 to fund the NHS. The government treated the taxpayers like the adults
that they are, explaining why the increase was necessary and what it would
fund. Taxpayers understood and were happy to support a service that is of the
utmost significance in our country, and the same is true today, with polls suggesting
that two-thirds of voters would be happy to pay more
in tax to save our NHS.
The scale of spending
Labour is planning is admirable (though should perhaps be scaled in over a
longer time period, and have a greater focus on welfare reform) but its fear of
raising taxes for the majority means that its spending ambitions are hard to
believe, and to the extent that they are achievable, there are unintended
consequences that have not been adequately addressed.
Issues of personal
interest.
Brexit policy.
Labour has been
surprisingly effective at de-branding this general election from the ‘Brexit
election.’ Focus
groups suggest that the
more a voter cares about Brexit, the harsher their feelings towards Labour, so
this plan is not an unreasonable one. The party has been effective at using
regular policy announcements to put its opponents on the back foot and redirect
a large part of the dialogue towards its bread and butter issues, such as the
NHS and nationalisation of utilities.
It is unfortunate
that Labour has had to largely duck out of the Brexit debate, since they have
the most sensible Brexit policy offered by any party. It is perhaps not
necessary to negotiate another deal with the EU but the desire to distance
themselves from Johnson’s adaptation of the May deal is understandable, and
given the party’s desire to renegotiate in terms more agreeable to the European
Union it seems likely that this would be achievable in the time frame they set
out.
The referendum that
they suggest - particularly given Corbyn’s recently stated intention of
remaining neutral during such a referendum - seems like the one course of
action that has the potential to reunify the country, or at least begin the
process of healing that is so desperately needed.
The case for a second
referendum is strong. In almost every voting intention poll, we have largely
seen only shuffling of voters between remain/referendum parties and shuffling
of voters between leave parties, with the vote split near 50/50 every instance.
This was reflected in the result of the European Parliamentary elections. We
have polls suggesting that for a large period of time now, the majority of the
public has been opposed to Brexit. Ironically enough, because of Brexit, an
extremely proud pro-European movement has emerged and changed the landscape
substantially. None of this is a guarantee that the majority of the electorate
would now support remaining in the EU, but that anyone that says they know with
certainty the will of the majority is lying.
Legitimate concerns
have been expressed regarding the perception that supporters of a second
referendum wish to overturn the result of the first - to ‘defy democracy.’
Retorts that allowing a vote can’t be undemocratic by definition are unhelpful,
and run contrary to practise we observe in the House of Commons that prevents a
Parliament being presented the same motion more than once in a given session.
We acknowledged recently that this convention is sensible for preventing
government from wearing down Parliament, and the analogy holds well for the
argument against repeated referendums. However, the kind of question being
suggested is substantially different to the question that was asked before, and
is a question that we need answering before embarking on the massive
constitutional change that leaving the EU represents.
The question asked in
2016 was inappropriate, and unjustifiably so given the precedent of the Scottish
referendum. What the public deserved was a concrete plan for what a post-EU
Britain would look like - and ideally what the transition would look like - in
the form of a white paper, so that the people’s instruction to the government
would be clear and deliverable. We were not given this. In the actual event, a
vote for leave to pursue a future of lower immigration looked the same as a
vote to leave to pursue a future of higher immigration from non-EU countries,
and a vote to leave and establish a more protectionist state looked the same as
a vote to leave and open trade negotiations with states not currently
negotiating with the EU. The instruction to the government was inherently and
inevitably unclear. A second referendum between two clearly defined options is
needed to rectify this.
Why two options, and
why the two that Labour are suggesting? The former question (annoyingly enough)
is essentially a mathematical problem, which is Arrow’s
impossibility theorem. This states that it is impossible for there to exist a ranked voting
system with more than two options that is ‘fair’ in a sense that maps safely
onto a common sense definition of fair. The result of a referendum which we
have every reason to expect will be exceptionally close and on such an
explosive issue will not reunify the country if it is the consequence of a
choice between imperfect voting systems. We cannot leave - or remain - on the
technicalities of hard-to-understand voting systems. The question needs to be
between two clear choices so that we can all agree on the winner and move
forward as one country.
Some have made the
argument that since we have already voted for leave (albeit in a very amorphous
form), the options on the ballot should be leave options. This seems to be
ill-founded logic. It is perfectly possible, given the tight margin of the 2016
referendum, that between remain and any specific form of leave the former would
win - perhaps by a significant margin - given that those who voted remain voted
for the same future, whereas it is likely that someone who voted for a Brexit
with greater immigration will not vote for a Brexit with lower immigration, and
someone who voted for a Brexit with more open borders will not vote for a
Brexit with less open borders. Given the reasonably high probability that this
is the case, it would surely be a bizarre situation in which this is not one of
the options available to voters. This is even ignoring the evidence that
suggests in a re-run of the 2016 referendum, the electorate would vote differently on account of what Brexit has revealed
of itself thus far.
What of the leave
option? Labour is quite right to insist that it must be a credible leave
option, which is to say, one that a majority of Parliament believes it can
genuinely implement without the cost to the public exceeding what is
acceptable. Perhaps it is the case that Johnson’s adapted May deal doesn’t
satisfy this criterion. However the deal that Labour are proposing, one with
access to the single market and inclusion in the customs union, seems to be
deliberately chosen as a non-starter for those who support leaving the European
Union. It is clearly not acceptable to transition from the current situation to
one which is identical except with reduced democratic participation and reduced
UK influence, but under Labour’s proposed deal, entailing as it would following
EU laws, denying the UK an independent trade policy, and requiring freedom of
movement, all without having any influence on these laws and the EU trade
policy is quite clearly a downgrade of our current situation. We should support
participation in the EU’s legal system so that we have access to a market which
would in any event influence UK production for EU export, a phenomenon known as
the Brussels effect. We should support freedom of movement for all the benefits
that a flexible labour force provides and for all the opportunity it provides a
UK citizen. But given that these questions (at least until recently) were those that were most important
to UK voters, it is incumbent on government to ensure that the electorate is
actually able to vote on them.
It is important to
notice that the two major issues with the currently negotiated deal are that it
allows a no-deal Brexit at the end of 2020, and that it splits Northern Ireland
from the rest of the United Kingdom. The former issue is not a problem if
the public vote for this deal under a Labour government, as they will be able
to make the decision to extend the transition period to allow for a more
ambitious and mutually beneficial trade agreement. The latter issue - that of
creating a customs border between Britain and Ireland, and by requiring that
Northern Ireland remains part of the single market of the EU, and not the
single market of the United Kingdom - is perhaps more terminal to the current
deal, and is perhaps best addressed if the ‘solution’ to the Irish border
question is restored to a full backstop. Perhaps the choice between remain and
May’s original deal with Johnson’s political declaration is that most
appropriate right now.
The public deserves a
choice between a genuine Brexit and to remain in the European Union. This is
perhaps not delivered exactly by the Labour pledge, but Labour are the party
offering the policy that is closest to this, and Corbyn’s intention to remain
neutral is the smartest decision that can be made in order to restore unity, by
preventing accusations of bias in implementing the decision, and to prevent
those with a more populist-bent aim from running a people vs government
campaign.
Council tax.
This is an issue of
personal interest to me and perhaps does not rate highly in the minds of most
voters, justifiably warranting its non-inclusion in the manifesto. Nonetheless,
it is an important issue. The attack of central government on local councils’
ability to raise revenue has been two-fold. The first and most obvious is the
dramatic cut in local council funding from central government; the second and
more antidemocratic measure has been to make it significantly harder for local
councils to raise more in council tax, implementing a policy whereby any
increase over 2.99% must be approved via referendum.
The former has
resulted in around 80% of local councils fearing
for their financial sustainability, and the reduction in many regions - particularly
rural areas that can provide fewer leisure services to raise revenue - of all
non-statutory spending, including libraries, youth centers, and all manner of
services that enrich our communities and bring local people together.
The latter has meant
that voters in local elections cannot be seriously offered the choice to
reverse these cuts. While some argue that the policy on raising council tax
represents a greater exercise in local democracy by handing this decision to
the voters, it is in fact a much weaker exercise. The requirement of a
referendum raises a serious impediment to locally elected officials being able
to raise and spend revenue in a manner consistent with their agenda. Any public
poll and the associated campaign require time, money, and effort to be put in
place - all three of which are exceedingly precious for strained local
councils, particularly noting that acting as a councillor is not a full time
job. The consequence of this is that such raises are almost never considered seriously,
even in long-held Labour wards. The policy is extremely effective in preventing
councils from acting out of lockstep with central government, and as such
represents a great harm to democratic principles. Further, this requirement
means that any candidates running on a platform of higher spending is unable to
promise to voters that they will be able to bring that vision to fruition,
since it relies on the uncertain outcome of an expensive and uncertain
referendum. Surely denying the electorate clarity in what they can expect from
the officials they choose to elect can only harm local democracy? When one
considers this Conservative policy and its Brexit policy, we see a certain
degree of irony that when it comes to issues such as raising local council tax,
local groups are expected to vote twice on the issue by the party that is
refusing a second vote on EU membership, and that a party that resents the
influence of a larger body of which it is a member still supports central
government imposing its will on local communities.
All of this is to say
that it is of the utmost importance that this policy is reversed, both for
practical reasons relating to desperate shortages of funds and for the
ideological purpose of strengthening of local democracy in the UK. It is
unfortunate that the Labour party has not seen this issue fit to include in its
manifesto, nor the issue of raising central funds for local councils, nor the
related issue of raising allowances awarded to councillors so they may be able
to focus on local governance full time.
Trust on foreign
policy.
As in 2017, the
Labour manifesto pledges to maintain and renew Trident, maintain spending 2% of
GDP on defence, and support our membership of NATO. These are all welcome
policies, though it could be argued that as climate change results in new sea
trade routes for Russia, and as the military is increasingly struggling for
funds, that defense spending needs to be increased, but that is a discussion
for elsewhere. The main concern is that these positions are at odds with the
position of Jeremy Corbyn and the leadership more broadly, and it is difficult
to trust that these promises will be honoured.
While it is beyond
unlikely that a Labour government would outright refuse to renew Trident, it is
possible they would pursue the policy only half-heartedly, providing
less-than-adequate funding or otherwise creating delays. While they would not
reduce defense spending, they may increase the scope for what is considered
defense spending to a degree beyond what an average person would reasonably
consider it to be. While they would not withdraw from NATO, it is possible that
they would take advantage of the flexibility in the phrasing of the article 5
treaty obligation for collective defence to not provide meaningful defence to
an attacked ally. The concern is not whether a Corbyn-lead government would
honour these manifesto pledges in word, but rather in fact.
Corbyn has no
enthusiasm for the armed forces, as he has made clear on several occasions, having
said that it would be
wonderful if every politician in the world decided to abolish their military.
This has been reported in many circles as a statement that Corbyn would abolish
the military, but surely this is the position that all of us hold? The world
would be a better place without war. That isn’t to say that military action
isn’t sometimes necessary, say to act against genocide as in Kosovo, but that the
world would be a better place if it were not should be a very uncontroversial
position.
More damningly,
however, is his imperative to “fight all the cuts, except those in the armed
forces, where we want to see a few more cuts taking place, and no more nuclear
weapons,” which he declared at a rally in 2010. This is hard to read as
anything other than a desire to not abolish the UK’s army, but definitely to
reduce its status. For completeness, it should be noted that in recent years
the Labour party commit to maintaining the UK’s status as a ‘tier one’ military
power, but this isn’t a well-defined term and it’s not hard to imagine that
such a hard campaigning and long standing anti-military Prime Minister would
seek to reduce military spending in some manner, perhaps as suggested above.
The case against
trusting Labour on the issue of Trident is clearer. The leadership has a
history of consistently breaking with the party whip and voting
against the renewal of Trident, he has a long and proud history of campaigning
for unilateral nuclear disarmament, and in 2015 leadership hustings he claimed
that he is against the renewal of Trident. Corbyn has regularly avoided
answering the question as to whether he would ever initiate a nuclear strike,
though it is worth noting that until recently it was not uncommon for Prime
Ministers to use a ‘constructive ambiguity’ regarding the use of nuclear
weapons, so this is not as inherently anti-nuclear a position as it may
initially seem. Thornberry has claimed that the decision on a nuclear strike
would be made collectively. This is of course not possible in the event that
Government is struck, and it is why one of the first acts of a prime minister
is to enclose in an envelope instructions for those manning the Trident
submarines in such an event. The opportunity for collective deliberation in
such a circumstance clearly does not exist, so such letters are a vital aspect
of our nuclear defense. Given the Labour leadership’s view on the nuclear
deterrent, it is not hard to imagine that the sending of such letters may be
much delayed, and that one may be concerned about the contents of such letters
if one supports the nuclear deterrent - we should bear in mind that the
principle behind a nuclear deterrent is that having it means you never have to
use it, so the contents of such letters may not be of great concern, though
their existence most certainly is. On the whole, it would be unfair to dismiss
concerns about how proactively or not a Labour government would pursue the
renewal of Trident.
Finally, regarding
NATO, Corbyn has on many occasions argued that the body is irrelevant since the end of the Cold War, and in
fact has described it as an attempt to provoke action from the USSR, as well as
describing it as an engine of oil delivery. Coupled with Corbyn’s voting record
indicating total opposition to all
military action, it is reasonable to be concerned with the party leadership’s
commitment to collective defense. All of this means that it is ultimately very
hard to trust the manifesto pledges on defense issues will be honoured in
sentiment, even if they are in word.
Paternity leave.
This is a policy
unlikely to attract any serious attention, but - and please indulge my brief
self-indulgence - I hope to one day be a father. I hope to do this not so that
after two weeks or four weeks I can see my child in passing on weekdays, and
not so I can provide my partner with the task of effectively raising our child
alone. Labour’s policy on paternity leave is to increase it from two weeks to
four weeks. This is disappointingly unambitious.
We can categorise
arguments for maternity leave roughly into two bins: arguments along the line
that mothers need time to recover after having given birth, and arguments that
early bonding between a mother and child is vital for healthy development.
While the justification of time for recovery clearly does not exist for fathers
as it does for mothers, if this is the sole justification and not concerns
regarding familial bonding, it still makes sense for mothers and fathers to
have roughly equivalent rights in this regard. If it is unfair to ask a new
mother to work for a certain amount of time as they need to recover, it is
unfair to ask a new mother to raise a child without support from their partner
for most of the week. If instead we justify maternity leave as beneficial for
the child, then this argument holds equally well for paternity leave. In either
case, we should support much greater reform in this area, and Labour’s pledge
is nowhere near enough.
There is an
additional gender equality aspect to a policy of roughly equal child leave
rights, which is that while gender discrimination is of course illegal in
hiring and pay, it of course exists. We see it in the data, in particular we
see a motherhood penalty, whereby women’s earnings and earnings growth drops
significantly after the birth of a child. It is not hard to imagine that the
potential for a worker to depart from work for six months to a year is priced
in by unscrupulous and immoral employers who are largely protected from the law
due to the nature of these cases being hard to try in court. In a society in
which this is a factor for any potential parent, one would expect this effect
to be absent. Along with preventing social concerns from affecting decision
making of new fathers, this means we should expect Labour to promote a
use-it-or-lose-it policy of paternity leave, as opposed to fully shared
parental leave. Of course, this manifesto suggests we are nowhere near that
situation.
Conclusion.
Labour has described
its manifesto as a manifesto of hope. There are great ambitions regarding our
response to the climate change crisis which threatens all of us, and modern
approaches to infrastructure investment. But to declare it a manifesto of hope
is to go too far. Where is the hope for those struggling in poverty but still
in work? Where is the hope for those who rely on the benefits system, when the
party has pledged to effectively undo only a
quarter of the cuts since 2010? Where is the hope that the UK public are
willing to contribute more to create a better society?
Ultimately forced to
choose between the party that offers this manifesto and the other parties.
Despite the problems this manifesto has regarding the aspects in which it’s
claimed ‘hope’ is lacking, and despite the concerns around the feasibility of
mobilising infrastructure investment as fast as Labour plans given available
capital, this is a positive document in many respects. It should be cheered for
its approach to the climate crisis, for its modern approach to infrastructure
spending, and for its education for life policy. The scale of the problems it
tackles is large and they have promised an equally large response, and given
the choice between this manifesto and any of the others, this is up their with
the best.
Comments
Post a Comment