The influence of the state on the economy is legitimised through two main aims: increasing the options available to the individual – and hence their liberty – by securing broad-based prosperity, and addressing externalities and frictions that the market cannot address, thereby also increasing prosperity, increasing the options open to individuals, and protecting individuals from unreasonable harm. These obligations create distinct pressures in the short-term and the medium-to-long-term. For the former, it is clear that right now, moves need to be made to address both the real-terms deprivation that households are experiencing and to address the closely related issue of excessive inflation that is rapidly eroding the value of people’s income. For the latter, the only sustainable way of improving broad-based prosperity is to increase productivity per hour worked, allowing incomes to grow or individuals to take increasing amounts of leisure time without sacrificing current living standards.
As an aside, this latter pressure does not mean that union
efforts are not vital in increasing wages. They are. And efforts should be made
to increase the bargaining power of unions to address unfairly low wages and
wage growth. It is, however, the case that the productivity of a worker is necessarily
a cap on the income that worker can receive – if a company were to pay every
employee more than the value of what they produced, the company would be
running a loss. More broadly, it couldn’t be the case for every company to do
this, as there simply wouldn’t be enough stuff made to do this. Therefore,
while structural changes are needed to improve pay, such structural changes can
only result in a one-off uplift in incomes, and hence can’t generate
sustainable increases independently of increases to productivity in the sense
that they can’t increase incomes indefinitely (though it should be noted that
some studies do show changes in organisational structures do influence
productivity).
The current crisis of stagflation – that is low or negative economic
growth coupled with high inflation – is the root of most of the government’s
current issues. Since the Bank of England was granted independence, it has perhaps
unfairly been left with assuming the burden of managing inflation, primarily
through the tool of controlling interest rates, or more accurately, the one-day
interest rate at which the Bank of England will lend to commercial banks, who
typically will pass changes in that rate onto their customers for both unbacked
loans and mortgages. It is the latter that has taken much attention in recent
discourse, and not without good reason.
The core of inflation is the disparity between changes in
the supply of currency and changes in the supply of goods and services. This
can be driven either by an over-supply of currency, or an under-supply of
goods. Making the incredibly bold assumption that consumption is for all goods
and services able to be continuously reduced with a correspondingly continuous
decrease in utility, we can understand one purpose of interest rate changes
rather simply: the act of increasing interest payments (primarily on mortgages)
means that currency has been eliminated from circulation, as more of people’s
income that they would have spent has gone to interest payments. That
assumption needs some clarification, and the reader should be aware that we’re
not uncritically accepting it, or indeed accepting it at a household level, as
will be explained below.
Informally, the assumption is simply that if one were to
reduce their consumption of a good, say, entertainment, by a small amount, then
the decrease in the utility or wellbeing resulting from that is also small.
Another way of saying this is that there are no cliff-edges. For a lot of goods
and services this is reasonable, but it’s not difficult to think of examples
where this isn’t the case – food, heat, and water are all goods where there is
obviously a point at which reduction in the good results in a massive decrease
in utility, corresponding to starvation, freezing, or thirst/unhygienic
environments. That economists often use this assumption is not evidence of any
sort of apathy to human suffering, but rather because it makes the mathematical
analysis of economic models tractable in a way they otherwise wouldn’t be. Some
modern economists have started exploring utility functions that don’t imply
this assumption (the interested and mathematically advanced reader should
consider looking up “generalised CES aggregators”), but much thinking is rooted
in the idea that consumers with lower income can just consume a bit less of a
wide range of goods and services when in reality this won’t hold, and reduction
of consumption in response to other variables isn’t feasible or is extremely
undesirable.
There are two main reasons that interest rates – a single
value – are not suited for the issue that is currently facing us. Firstly, is
the shotgun approach it takes to the population. Simply put, for a lot of
people, over-consumption isn’t the problem, and for these people consumption
can’t be reined in much more than it already has. This has the additional issue
that increases in mortgage interest payment rates don’t have the intended
affect. It’s unavoidable that they reduce lifetime consumption – the
expenditure of increased interest payments comes from somewhere, and it’s hard
to imagine that it has any stimulating effect on a household’s income – but
it’s not a foregone conclusion that reduction is achieved in the present.
Currently the UK is seeing many homeowners who are reaching the end of their
fixed term rates extending the term of their loans so that monthly repayments
remain roughly the same. For many, this is likely because consumption can’t be
reasonably reduced. For the same reason, many have started dipping into their
savings, rather than cutting consumption. This means that the effect of
interest rate rises in reducing inflation by reducing consumer demand doesn’t
happen in the current period. Given that the intention of raising short-term
rates is to affect short-term variables, depressing consumption far in the
future of these households (particularly the period in which they had planned
to have finished paying off their mortgages and will now still be paying, or
when they had originally intended to draw down from their savings) does nothing
to help any macroeconomic aim and only depresses the long-term wellbeing of
households.
Worse than that, households that own their home outright are
the only demographic that aren’t harmed by increases in interest rates
increasing the interest rates on mortgages. The ways in which mortgage-holders
are affected is obvious, but renters will suffer similarly as their landlords
raise their rents to accommodate increased mortgage payments or as landlords
who own properties outright increase rents to take advantage of the market
conditions. The only demographic spared is the third of households that own
their homes outright – households that are wealthier and better placed to
withstand reduced disposable income, simply because they have more of it.
Secondly, the function that maps interest rates to
everything we care about is under-specified, in that the range of this function
is multivalued; we care not only about the rate of inflation, but also about
growth, unemployment, homeownership, and living standards. Without exceedingly
good luck, this is mathematically doomed to failure. If I have a function, say
the square root of x; another function, the square of x; and a target that the
first function should be exactly 6, it would be unreasonable for me to then
introduce the target that the second function must be below 900, as the first
target requires that x be set to 36, and the second target requires that x be
below 30.
Fortunately, if we are to understand the effect of interest
rates as being the elimination of currency from circulation, then we only have
to look to fiscal policy to find a tool that can be applied far less bluntly to
achieve the same goal: taxation. This line of thinking borrows much from modern
monetary theory, and while we should be cautious of uncritically adopting
models that depart from orthodoxy and which can be used to motivate policies we
already advocate, the argument is hard to refute. In any case, an analogous
(though perhaps clunkier) motivation can come from a more explicitly Keynesian
framework. The general idea is that taxation does not pay for government
activity in a direct sense by taking existing money. Instead, currency is introduced
into the economy by the state through state spending on both capital
expenditures and current expenditures such as wages and benefits. The purpose
of tax is to then eliminate a correlated amount of currency in order to not introduce
more currency into circulation than real value generated by this spending,
hence avoiding inflation. Without tax acting in this way, the amount of money would
increase more than the amount of stuff that people want, allowing people to bid
more money on any given good.
By setting tax appropriately, currency can be eliminated
from the economy in a way that doesn’t cause extreme hardship, namely through
progressive taxation. Instead of everyone facing a sudden loss of disposable
income through increased interest payments, which increase by the same
proportion for all, we can protect the disposable income of those earning the
lowest, and increase taxes on incomes over a certain value (through whatever
tax is preferable, be it income tax, national insurance contributions, or capital
gains tax). At its simplest, this would represent increasing the value of
higher rates of income taxes or national insurance contributions. That said,
the state has complete discretion over how it chooses to delete money in the
economy through tax, and so while the current typical adjustments in tax are finite
vectors (that is, any change in tax can be described by the rates of each tax
band and the thresholds for each tax band), the options open to the state are
much wider. For the purpose of taxation being simple to understand – which is
important, as individuals should be able to easily predict and understand the
way in which the state is going to confiscate their income – tax as a function
of income should probably be restricted to piecewise linear functions, which are
functions composed of straight lines that change steepness at certain points,
but this still leaves plenty of room for the state to address inflationary
concerns while protecting living standards. This means that fiscal policy, as
opposed to changes in interest rates, can successfully target multiple metrics
in a way that interest rates are fundamentally unable to. Such a policy also
has the advantage of not being able to be circumvented by measures such as
extending the terms of repayment.
It should be noted for full completeness that addressing
inflation through progressive taxation is a choice. It’s one that we should
take, because it is vital that no one in the UK choose between heating and
eating, or face homelessness. But taming inflation through a progressive tax
would entail confiscating more of the population’s income than some alternative
fiscal policy. This is because the effect of fiscal policy on inflation is
affected by people’s propensity to consume – the proportion of their income
they spend on consumption, where consumption is understood to be the
alternative to saving. Household’s propensity to consume is a decreasing
function of their income and wealth. Poorer households spend a higher
proportion of their income than richer households. The higher the propensity to
consume, the greater the effect of a change in income on inflation as more of
that increased or decreased income will be put into or removed from
circulation. Indeed, if the only role of the state was redistribution, it would
be the case that to maintain an inflation rate of zero, the state would have to
run a surplus – where we now understand this to mean that the state removes
more money through tax than it adds through spending, or in this case than it
gives out through benefits. If it instead ran a balanced budget, the same
amount of money would exist, but because it has been shifted from those with a
lower propensity to spend to those with a higher propensity to spend that total
demand in the economy would increase, thus driving inflation. To be clear,
targeting an inflation rate of zero would not be desirable for a variety of
reasons that aren’t of interest here, and the state should absolutely not only
act to redistribute income and should instead be fiscally active in other ways
such as developing public infrastructure, but this illustration is useful in
understanding how varying propensities to consume interact with systems of
progressive tax. If we chose to address inflation with progressive tax changes,
we would be taxing more than we would otherwise have to. I would strongly argue
that this is worthwhile and to do otherwise would be unbecoming of us as a society,
but there are legitimate ideological disagreements to be had here.
While we’ve so far discussed
how interest rates effects consumer demand through mortgages (and the
downstream effects on the rental market), it’s worth noting that another way in
which higher interest rates are intended to reduce inflation by reducing demand
is by also disincentivising businesses from taking on debt to finance investment.
Investment entails demand for inputs to expansion such as raw materials and
services. More investment means more demand for these inputs, which means more
inflation. As opposed to mortgages, this does have an immediate effect.
What’s unfortunate
is that the UK is struggling with investment already. Underinvestment has
resulted in productivity-growth of virtually zero since the financial crisis –
a situation not seen in comparison countries – and we are currently in a crisis
of not having enough stuff rather than having too much demand for stuff; hence
why many households simply can’t reduce consumption. Were productivity higher
inflation would be weaker, as the rate of increase in the amount of stuff
people want would be higher and therefore closer to the rate of increase in
circulating currency. The issue of productivity is directly related to that of
inflation, and vice versa as increased inflation decreases ability to invest.
Addressing the
short-term issue of appropriate inflation rates and the medium-to-long-term
issue of low productivity growth arising from under-investment is difficult. In
all likelihood, the consensus that there is just no combination of policies
that lead to a painless recovery is correct. Since there is a lag between
investment and increased productivity, any boost to investment will have an
inflationary effect due to increased demand before it has a deflationary effect
due to increased supply.
That said, we also
exist in a context where some investment can’t wait. The industries supplying
means to mitigate or adapt to climate change need to massively expand, ideally
twenty years ago, but failing that, now. Delay isn’t an option and previous
delay is why a focus on adaptation measures is now a priority alongside
mitigation measures that reduce GHG emissions while maintaining living
standards. The health and social care sector and the education sector need to invest
in higher salaries to address the issue of talent being lost to other countries
offering better incomes to doctors, nurses, and teachers, or to other groups in
the private sector seeking the same skillsets and willing to pay for them.
Analogously to the ways in which tax should act to deal out enforced reductions
in demand through currency elimination among households in a way that is fair
and commensurate with each household’s ability to bear this rather than the
broad brush of interest rate rises, the UK must similarly identify industries
that can’t wait to grow and craft taxes so that the industries which need to
bear the current brunt of restrictions in investment are incentivised to do so.
This again is within the power of the state as it determines fiscal policy.
Ultimately, interest
rates are too blunt a tool for what we need right now. This isn’t to argue that
interest rates aren’t legitimate and that rate changes aren’t necessary. Debt
and credit are legitimate items and necessary for smoothing income and
consumption over a lifetime, and there needs to be an incentive for people to
make loans which is interest. It’s just not clear that monetary policy is a
better tool than fiscal policy in addressing the UK’s current malaise. It’s
possible it’s the only tool that’s perceived to be politically palatable – tax
is often perceived as sticky (that is, difficult or slow to change), and it is
useful for a democratically elected government to be able to blame an
independent body for households’ hardships. For taxes to be used in this way
would require a shift in thinking as well as legislative changes – perhaps specifying
in the budget a range over which tax rates can vary as opposed to a fixed value.
Until the state acknowledges the role of fiscal policy in maintaining
appropriate levels of inflation while still attacking medium-to-long-term
goals, there will be more suffering than there needs to be.
Comments
Post a Comment